Unfortunately I read Greg Mankiw's of Harvard paper (Title: The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer --in pdf) right after giving last lecture of intermediate macroeconomics, with topic on the stabilization policy (the birth of, Keynesian, macroeconomics) and the subsequent New Macroeconomics. If not, I would like to add it as reading list. For non economists, don't worry, it's a non-technical paper (read: no math). You can take it as the biography of the macroeconomics.
In that paper, before coming into a rather disheartening verdict on the disconnection of macroeconomics as science and as engineering (or problem solving) Mankiw draws a very clear and readable history of macroeconomics as a discipline. Soon you would be engaged in a gripping tale on the battle of ideas between Keynesian and New Keynesian in one hand, and New Classical in the other.
In page 12 Lucas was quoted saying:"People don't take Keynesian theorizing seriously anymore"
While Solow called that it"foolishly restrictive" for the new classical economists to rule out by assumption the existence of wage and price rigidity and the possibility that markets do not clear.
Meanwhile the science itself develops in both camp of neoclassical and neo Keynesian (modern macroeconomics, you would like to say). The interesting research projects of the two schools have been discussed briefly, but excellently, in the paper. Both leads to a conclusion that now we know better about the subject.
ButIf God put macroeconomics on earth to solve the problems, then the Saint Peter will ultimately judge us by our contributions to economic engineering. So let’s ask: Have the developments in business cycle theories over the past several decades improved the making of economic policy? p.15
footnotes:
* yeah, it's Karl Marx's word, not on macroeconomists, but philosophers who are too busy interpret the world in various ways.
aha, an asterisk on post title... that's too gay...
ReplyDeleteMaybe we don't really need revolutionary ideas, says Lindauer and Pritchett:
ReplyDeletehttp://muse.jhu.edu.ezp1.harvard.edu/journals/economia/v003/3.1lindauer.pdf
(d'oh.. how to create links in comments..??)
Manager, I know sometimes you have hard times taking care of the cafe. But apparently you read and take this book Overheard in New York too seriously :-). It may give you wrong ideas, mate :-).
ReplyDeleteAnd Michael Franks? d'oh.
ap, can't open the link.
ReplyDeleteAre you saying that we'd better stay with Keynesian model? :-)
For me it'd be cool to see such revolution by the way :-)
Sorry,
ReplyDeletehere is the article. if you can't open it, the title is "What’s the Big Idea? The Third Generation of Policies for Economic Growth" by Lant Pritchett and David Lindauer.
the argument says: perhaps we don't need new 'big' ideas in economics. the question is how to apply the previous ideas and do it right.
on Keynes, sorry for the Keynesian, Pritchett and Lindauer mentioned than Keynesian was only powerful until the 1970s. Because after that, macro policy has been oriented towards price stablization, meaning switching from Keynesian to neoclassic.
for Robert Barro, this is a switch from JM Keynes to Friedman. he said "in terms of intellectual battle, Friedman has won it."
Michael Piore, my Pol. Econ professor at the MIT amen to that by saying, "Friedman won the battle not only in policy perscription, but also in explaining how the world works..."
Krugman will not agree ("Why aren't we all Keynesian?". so won't the late John K Galbraith.
ap, what policy prescription? Mankiw shows us --and I tend to agree-- that the latest development in theories (be it neoclassicals or new keynesian)are not (yet) incorporated into macroeconomic model of the policymakers. So much for Friedman-ite mania spreading around the world, the framework is still very much Keynesian.
ReplyDeleteEven Fischer, Dornbusch, and Startz (2000) in their textbook of Macroeconomics put it bluntly: While the intellectual appeal of rational expectations models is very strong, the empirical evidence is less supportive
Well, I was talking about the actual policies that were implemented. Clearly that since the 1970s macro policies were oriented towards (among other things):
ReplyDelete1. balanced budget, or at least fiscal discipline
2. controlling inflation through monetary policy (NOT aggregate demand policy -- "inflation is always and forever a monetary phenomenon)
We can also add the views on crowding out fiscal policy, the neutrality of government bonds etc.
I am not saying those are the most correct ones. But those were the dominant views.