
Friday, November 14, 2008
Minimum wages and SME

Wages, unemployment and formal employment

Second, (B) and (C) can be divided into three periods. Prior to the crisis (1998), all went well in the sense that wage was growing, and so was formal sector employment. From 1999-2003, when wages was increasing rapidly, share formal sector employment declined significantly. After 2003, wages has been relatively stagnant. It is no coincidence that formal sector employment started to expand.
Note: 1) you won't see the relations as significant if you just simply take one point of time and compare it to another (say, 1999 vs. 2008). 2) a colleague of mine did an econometric estimation and confirmed that every 10% increase in average regional minimum wages is associated with 1 percentage point decline in the share of formal sector employment a year later.
Third, I didn't put it on the picture -- but apparently there is an obvious relations between wages and unemployment. Our friend Suahasil Nazara and his co-author Iyanatul Islam might be right (like Card and Krueger). But I second Prof. Aris Ananta that unemployment rate may not be the best labor market indicator, as it doesn't tell much about job quality and welfare. In such case, formal sector employment should be a better indicator.
Now the question is who wins and who loses if the minimum wage is increased?
Sunday, June 29, 2008
Six and Eleven Thousands
They deemed the ratio, those numbers, as irrelevant, because it all depends on, well.., something else. Of course, numbers might not give you complete answers, the wrong numbers can be disastrous too. But it does have some useful information.
Consider this:
a. The Ministry of Finance has surplus of incompetent officers but at the same time lacks of badly needed officers, such as tax inspectors.
b. The Ministry of Finance has surplus of six thousands incompetent officers but at the same time lacks of eleven thousands more badly-needed officers, such as tax inspectors.
Which one is more useful information? Alas, even the so called experts are too
The first step to public reform, of course, to know how many people we need to hire --and scrap out--, given the needs in hand.
Saturday, November 24, 2007
Footballnomics #9: are foreigners to blame for England's failure?
For one, the English team have never been great. Before the EU single market that revolutionized the football transfer market in the early 1990s, when there were only three foreign players allowed to play, England never won anything except the 1966 World Cup (the only trophy they have ever won). So the number of foreign players in the English League can not explain the national team's performance.
And remember, the EU open labor market also applied to the other countries. Foreign players have been coming en masse to France, Germany or Italy. Yet these countries won the 1998, 2002 and 2006 World Cup respectively (Germany also won the European Cup in 1996, and France in 2000).
Some people argued that foreign players have limited the chance of English players to play or be recruited by top teams. That is simply because English players are too expensive, given their (average) quality. To judge the quality of English players, just look at how many Englishmen play in the continent at the top leagues. Currently, none. At its peak, four (Owen, Beckham and Woodgate in Madrid, Hargreaves in Bayern Muenchen; altogether, only them plus Gascoigne and Ince in the 1990s who have ever played abroad).
Italy can have a stronger team because their best players can still outcompete foreigners in Serie A. The French League, on the other hand, is less competitive than the EPL, Serie A or La Liga. There are a lot of foreigners, mainly from Africa, in the French League. But the best of French players are good enough to be the best players in England, Italy or Spain.
In short, the Englishmen can not blame globalization for their crappy performance. Globalization brings competition. It exposes the country's weaknesses that come out because of domestic problems.
Update: I forgot to mention David Platt and Steve McManaman as the other English players who have played in the top European Leagues in the 1990s. Also, Kevin Keegan did it in the early 1980s.
Friday, June 29, 2007
Footballnomics #6: Fabio Capello
Capello's departure seems to be a strange decision, given the fact that he brought the La Liga title in his first year (well, his first year of the second term at Madrid). But then, just like players, the manager job market is not like a standard labor market. So we need more than the standard labor economic analysis to understand what happens.
As Leo Tolstoy once said, "All happy families are alike. All unhappy families are unhappy in their on ways." All happy, job-secured managers have these conditions met: have a good relationship with the club, players and supporters, and is able to achieve the expectations of the club's stakeholders given the budget. With the exception of Jose Mourinho, Lose one of these conditions, and most likely you are heading somewhere.
That, perhaps, what happened to Capello. In the basic principal-agent setting, a manager is an agent acting on behalf the principal, who has some certain objectives. One may think that bringing the league title means that the objective is met. True, if it is the (only) objective. Looks like Madrid's board of directors has a greater set of objectives in their mind, which Capello could not deliver:
- A Champions League title
- Higher revenue (losing Beckham means losing a big source of revenue)
- A certain type of 'style' in playing football
- The directors' health. The board may be forward looking. If every year the title has to be won in the very last minutes, it would be bad for their heart condition, and the club's financial position if they have to pay the medical benefit. After calculating this potential expenses, even after considering the club's obligation to pay Capelllo's GBP 4m annual salary for the remaning 2 years of his contract, it is still beneficial for the club to terminate the deal.
Wednesday, June 06, 2007
Footballnomics #5: transfer market
Apart from that, explaining (or modeling) the transfer market is indeed a challenging task. What makes a club willing to pay GBP20m or more for a player (and pay him another 100k a week)? The player market is different from the regular labor market. It does not deal with labor with homogenous characteristics. It is rather a monopolistic competition market because each player have a monopoly over his skills that distinguish him from other players, which are observable by clubs. In the standard labor market, each workers have different skill. But firms can not observe each individuals, so they look at the pool of similar workers, and the market wage is the average earning of an average worker. Consequently, we cannot exactly draw the market demand/supply curve for player. (Therefore, it is more relevant to compare player market with the market for executive or other professionals).
Note:
* According to the Bosman rule, 6 months before his contract expires, the player can sign a pre-contract with the new club. That's why when clubs want to keep their star players, they must negotiate a new contract when the players are as far as 2 years away from the end of their contracts. If the negotiation collapse, the club at least will be able to sell the player at the beginning of his final season.
** If the club gets a player for free, that means the club has more money to increase the salary. Hence, we see many 'free' players have higher salary level.
Thursday, November 23, 2006
When excess supply is a win-win
Let's see:
- Policy is supposed to be effective, agree? (Otherwise, what's the point of making a policy?)
- Now, for a minimum wage policy. What is 'effective'? Effective minimum wage is when wage can not go lower than that, agree?
- What is 'compromise' between supply and demand? It is a situation where supply meets the demand (or demand meets the supply, whatever), no? Economists call it 'equilibrium'.
- Now, if supply and demand meet, is there any excess? No. Because if there is, it is not an equilibrium. Not a 'compromise'.
- So, in order to be effective, a minimum wage should be higher than equilibrium wage. That means, it should be such that an excess supply is in effect.
- In other words, the title of the news is at best, misleading.
More coffee, please?
Econ Fallacy
Monday, August 14, 2006
Econ301: Education and labor market signaling
Updated note: a version of this entry was published in The Jakarta Post (15/8/06).
Why do many people hopes to get higher education, university degree in this case?
The most common answer is because having a university degree makes it easier to find job. Actually, this is not the correct answer. Several researches have shown that people with high school diploma or lower have greater chance to be employed or to switch jobs. Especially after the economic crisis, people with higher education are more likely to be employed.
What does the model imply?
The signaling model changed the way people looked at how labor market works. The fact that signaling mechanism partly, or mostly, determines the market wage setting has an important implication. University degree helps increasing wage as long as those with university diploma accounts for only a small fraction in the labor market. When the share of university graduate grows, it will no longer be an effective signal. Employers will look for new type of signals to distinguish workers, such as more advance degrees (Master’s, Ph.D.), professional degrees (CPA, CFA), or graduating from 'top' universities (err... UI?).
Saturday, July 15, 2006
If Looks Could Kill
a. driving down the domestic wage (the case of US immigration law debate, not so long ago)Okay, you may say, in the end, it is all about fear of competition.
b. local customer protection against low services provided by foreigners
c. cream-skimming and creating inequity
d. crowding out the domestic worker's employment.
But after reading a short article in The Jakarta Post 13/07/06 (alas, no link) on Malaysia's recent policy to lift the ban on Bangladeshi workers, you may want to add up one more reason. But let me quote part of the article first:
Malaysia restricted the number of Bangladeshi workers in the country in 1996 and banned them entirely two years ago, after it said they were creating social problems by entering into romantic liasions with local women.Yes, it is love and good looks that prevent a country from gaining profit from international trade in services.
Officials have said the Bangladeshis, who looked like Indian movie stars to some local women, had seduced and eloped with them.
For me, it doesn't sound right for two things: First of all, it undermines fair competition both in labor market and, more importantly, love market. Second, it implies that foreign workers with good looks actually don't have as big an opportunity as those who are less fortunate in that area.
Talk about male chauvinist pigs. Come off it. Let the competition go on
Addendum:
A self-reflection on our profession, for university teacher, does looks matter? Yes, it does for having higher instructional rating, as Hamermesh and Parker (in pdf) say (via Greg Mankiw's blog), particularly, alas, for male teacher. Yet whether it reflects productivity gap or discrimination is probably impossible to judge. Gosh, somehow I feel relieved by this caveat.
p/s: From that paper, I like a punchline from supermodel Linda Evangelista: It was God who made me so beautiful. If I weren't, then I'd be a teacher. Yes, yes, we call it division of labour. It'd be more efficient this way.
economics of beauty | labor
Thursday, May 04, 2006
How more, not less, globalization can be beneficial for low skilled workers
I agree with the first statement that there is indeed this irony: on one hand the US government is trying to curb the flow of undocumented immigrants, while on the other hand, US businesses and households are taking advantage of these (illegal) immigrants. But I can't disagree more with her second statement - the globalization-poverty nexus. If anything, loosening immigration, thereby implying more globalization in the form of increasing labor mobility may be the fastest way to equalize the wages for unskilled workers between Mexico and the US. By doing so, it also has the enormous potential to help reduce poverty south of the border. I am more sympathetic with Rizal's view:
"...if what we mean by globalization is a free mobility of factor of production, how can we simply put aside the labor movement --itself a very significant, if not the most crucial, factors of production beside capital and goods?"Like Rizal, I also tend to believe that more globalization, not less, in the form of high mobility of labor can be beneficial for the low-skilled workers from poor countries.
To drive this point further, an article by Stephan Faris at Salon is worth discussing. While he was living in Nairobi as a journalist for Time, he employed in his household the following: a nanny, a maid, a gardener, and a watchman, all for a combined daily wages less than the cost of the main course when he went out for dinner. All that was possible because he "drew Western salary and paid African wages" (a situation many expats in Indonesia may have no problem relating to). But he is smart enough to leave his troubled conscience behind and wrote:
"...Those who squirm at the idea of having servants should consider that there's little moral difference between me and my maid, and those who buy a washing machine whose low cost depends on other people's deflated wages. We've globalized capital, but not labor. A washing machine manufacturer can cash in on China's low wages, but the Chinese factory worker is barred from taking a boat to seek better pay. He's forced to sell his labor at much lower than the global market value. Both my maid and the factory worker would prefer to work for Western wages. But they can't because of immigration restrictions..."Indeed. The main reason why people emigrate to other countries is to take advantage of the differences in potential earnings (Massive Movement of Refugees and IDPs and Chronic and Sustained Human Flight notwithstanding). Why wage discrepancies for the same skill level exist and why they persist are obviously determined by various things (e.g. endowment, technology, institution etc., see this for a simple yet powerful exposition). But perhaps one of the most important things that prevent these discrepancies to disappear is the set of immigration restrictions. Even with restrictions in place, the potential emigrants may internalize the cost and still view that the wage discrepancies are still worth taking the risks for.
Sounding like an economist, Faris then argues that:
"...From the standpoint of economic theory, liberalizing the flow of labor is no different from liberalizing trade. Both redistribute a nation's wealth, with a net positive effect. The difference is that liberalizing trade disproportionately benefits richer countries, while easing immigration restrictions would help the world's poor..."*)Moreover, in most if not all countries, immigration restrictions disproportionally hold back the movement of low-skilled labors. A PhD in molecular science would be in better position to come to the US than a high school graduate (it is tempting to talk about brain drain and some misconceptions about it at this point but let's not). On the other hand, or rather because of it, the potential gains for unskilled workers are likely to be greater because the factor market for these unskilled workers is not as integrated as the one for highly-skilled labors. By loosening the immigration restrictions for low-skilled workers the dreams of better lives for them may be realized sooner. Even if it means that we need more globalization.
*) Some may be put off by any statement that begins with "From the standpoint of economic theory". But even the accidental darling of anti-globalization movement, Joseph Stiglitz, has the following message buried in his powerpoint file (see page 45) about the state of development in Latin America:
" The successful countries have actually followed models which are more in accord with economic theory than the Washington consensus "Addendum:
(Hat tip to Martin for the link to the file)
Tyler Cowen of the Marginal Revolution fame and DanielRothschild wrote an op-ed in LA Times (via, what else, Marginal Revolution), addressing the same debate. Here's a quote:
"A key question for economists has been whether the influx raises or lowers"native" American wages. UC Berkeley's David Card, who studied patterns in different U.S. cities, concludes that immigration has not lowered wages for American workers. George Borjas of Harvard counters that immigration reduced the wages of high school dropouts by 7.4% between 1980 and 2000.In the op-ed, Cowen and Rothschild also label Borjas as "the favorite economist of immigration restrictionists", an assertion I suspect many economists would also not find difficulties to side with.
Most economists have sided with Card."
Globalization labor
Thursday, February 09, 2006
Who wants labor market inflexibility?
In their sociological research, they particulary concern that labor market flexibility would degrade the labor condition and job security --and argue that due this flexibility there's a shift of permanent employment to non-permanent one (outsourcing, contract, etc) so that the labor's wealth and income becomes less certain.
My take: it is the labor market IN-flexibility that causes all of those problems abovementioned. In fact, so far our labor market is not yet flexible. The inflexibility imposes high cost for firms to hire permanent workers --and to fire when necessary(the severance payment is as high as 10 months salary, according to a fellow discussant from CSIS)--. Therefore the firms opt to hire non-permanent workers.
It seems to me that they're alarmed by the current formal worker's job security status, but as you may know the labor market rigidity harms the ones who are outside the formal sector --the unemployed and the informal sector's worker. It is a trade-off indeed between employment creation and job security of the labors already within formal sector.
Moreover, another discussant from SMERU revealed a bad news: he estimates that 1% economic growth may only absorb 225K employment --way below the government's figure. And according to our CSIS fellow, there is a recent shift from labor intensive to capital intensive investment --to partly confirm the low employment absorption.
Labor Market
Friday, December 16, 2005
Down with the minimum wage
My mother hire two maids. In Jakarta, it's normal to pay 700 to 800 thousand rupiahs to a maid each month. Say it's 800,000. Now imagine that the government require households to comply with the minimum wage law. For Jakarta, it's Rp 1 million. What would my mother do? Well, she might give up one maid, and hire only one. Or, if she ever thought to hire a third one, she would cancell that. In the first case, my mother would send one person to unemployment. In the second case, my mother could have created one employment, but thanks to the minimum wage law, she called it a no.What's the moral here? Minimum wage law is good only for those already in the job and who are lucky not to get kicked out by the saving employer. Minimum wage law is bad for unemployment.
You might ask: but minimum wage law is not required for households. What difference is there between companies and my mother?
Sunday, November 06, 2005
Education creates employment, or the other way round?
On a different case, but pretty similar, this guy just decided to quit Harvard because the marginal return of another year at Cambridge, MA 02138 is very small (even negative?).